Verified Document

Absolute Advantage And Theory Literature Review

Adam Smith's theory of absolute advantage and Ricardo's theory of comparative advantage offer two economic approaches to international trade. Each theory contributes to the field of international economics in different ways. This literature review will compare the two theories through the lens of scholarly articles published on the respective subjects. By the 18th century (1776 to be exact), the development of international trade had reached a critical nexus: the colonies in America had revolted against the British Crown and a revolutionary character was evident throughout much of Western society. (The French would have their own Revolution before the century was out). Tackling the question of economic theory and its place in trade (in the light of this emerging climate) was Adam Smith with his massive treatise Wealth of Nations. Smith's concern focused on the specialization of labor -- the ability of producers to divide labor into parts to maximize output and achieve the greatest amount of profit as a result. When this theory was applied to international trade, a vision of all the countries of the world competing in a global marketplace emerged. As Smith pointed out, in a mercantilist system it would not be possible for all countries to maximize profitability if all were exporting more than they imported. Instead of placing harsh restrictions on imports and aggressively pursuing exports, Smith suggested that the theory of specialization be applied to trade and that a system of free trade be developed in which countries specialized in exporting only those items in which they had absolute advantage. Absolute advantage was defined thus: according to Smith's theory, some countries would be better than others at producing certain items -- such as cloth or wheat -- and therefore the better producer would be said to have absolute advantage over the other. It would therefore be in both countries interests (in terms of saving hours/labor) for the country with absolute advantage in producing a specific item to export it and for the other country to import it and vice-versa. In short, all countries would benefit through specialization and free trade: this was the heart of absolute advantage. The contribution it made to the field of international economics was that a system of free trade can in fact -- and must -- replace a mercantilist form of trade in the modern era.

However, if a country had no absolute advantage whatsoever, what would become of it? How would it ever profit in international trade? David Ricardo attempted to answer this question in 1817 when, building on the concept of absolute advantage, he devised the theory of comparative advantage. This theory held that even if a country does not have absolute advantage over another, it may have comparative advantage in that its labor productivity ratios are better. For Ricardo, labor was "the only source of value," which is why he devised the equation price = [rate of wages x labor production] / output. Thus, if a country's price of wheat was cheaper than in another country as a result of labor ratios, it would be able to be profitable in international trade (Chipman, 1966). Therefore, the contribution Ricardo's theory made to the field of international economics was that it showed that absolute advantage is not necessary for all countries to be profitable in free trade: comparative advantage is really all that is needed.

While both theories have been extremely important for modern economics, each has its limitations -- mainly because of the innumerable variables...

Parts of this document are hidden

View Full Document
svg-one

As models or foundations of economic thought they are helpful instruments -- and as Schumacher (2012) notes, it is thanks to Smith that economists today can assert with confidence that "international trade exploits the quantitative and qualitative benefits of an extended division of labor" (p. 60). Yet, while "trade and development cannot be separated in Smith's theory," what happens when development breaks down (Shumacher, 2012, p. 60) -- i.e., what happens when social, political and economic infrastructures taken as norms two hundred years ago no longer apply? Ricardo's theory can help to fill the gap by indicating that a comparative balance may always be achieved -- but even here the framework can be exploited in such a way that the desired balance is not achieved but rather heavily tilted towards one side or the other. Such is, after all, the effect of off-shoring as evidenced by "free" trade agreements such as GATT and NAFTA. Understanding how Smith's theory and Ricardo's theory work in the real world today is important because, after all, what is past is prologue -- and preparing for tomorrow cannot be achieved until what happened yesterday is firmly comprehended.
As Shumacher (2012) notes, Smith takes an "optimistic view of growth and economic progress" (p. 60-61). In 1776, one can hardly blame him for doing so: revolution was happening in the West -- progress the buzzword -- Equality and Liberalism about to be literally enthroned and exalted in Paris. Yet, less than half a century later, Ricardo was already dealing with some of the more unpleasant realities of international trade, business and economics -- the reality that lofty ideals as put forward by revolutionaries do not always find purchase in the cold, hard world of business. In an attempt to reconcile the optimism and good faith of Smith with the encroaching realism of the 19th century, Ricardo took up Smith's theory and began to adapt it: countries without any absolute advantage should still be able to compete. In order to support this belief, all that Ricardo required was a new way to describe value. He turned not to capital but to labor -- as did many minds in the 19th century. This trick, promoting labor as the basic source of all value, helped provide economic minds with a working framework for approaching international trade and economics; however, no one could have predicted that with the rise of the Industrial Revolution, a re-balancing of world powers, and, finally, the dawn of the Digital Age, the basic unit of value -- labor -- would need to be reassessed all over again. Value would need to be re-described, relocated, re-identified. What had been valuable to the 19th century mind was now worlds away from what was valuable to the 21st century mind.

From this perspective -- the perspective of time -- the two theories can be compared and contrasted as well: Smith's theory depends upon specific…

Sources used in this document:
References

Chipman, J. (1966). A survey of the theory of international trade. Econometrica, 34(1):

18-76.

Costinot, A., & Donaldson, D. (2012). Ricardo's theory of comparative advantage: Old idea, new evidence. Papers and Proceedings, 102(2): 1-6.

Das, M. (2008). Absolute and comparative advantage. International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, 2nd Edition. NY: Macmillan.
Cite this Document:
Copy Bibliography Citation

Related Documents

Economic Growth and Happiness Economic Growth Can
Words: 1551 Length: 6 Document Type: Essay

Economic Growth and Happiness Economic Growth Can Lead to Healthier and Happier Societies More Availability of Goods Higher Income Increase in Tax Revenues and Better Welfare Programs. Increase in Purchasing Power Technological Advancement Health Industry Benefits Business Sector Benefits General Benefits Reflective statement Economic Growth Can Lead To Healthier and Happier Societies Economic growth has long been termed as the precursor to any society's success, and in this paper, we shall be looking at various aspects of economic growth that are directly

Economic Globalization Has the 2008 Financial Meltdown
Words: 2832 Length: 11 Document Type: Essay

Economic Globalization Has the 2008 financial meltdown in the U.S. And the ongoing economic crisis in Europe have practically ended the era of economic globalization? Following the financial crisis that marred the U.S. economy along with other global economies as well as the ongoing Eurozone debt crisis, there have been projected concerns that this predicament would end economic globalization. The purpose of this paper is to assess this claim. Going by Immanuel

Economic Final Report
Words: 1317 Length: 4 Document Type: Term Paper

Economic Final Report Types of economic systems Economic systems vary from one nation to another. Traditional economic systems refer to an economic system founded by tradition. The services and goods that people provide through the work they do, how people exchange and use the resources are trends that follow permanent patterns. These are not dynamic economic systems because there are minimal changes. In this economic system, people live on static standards. They

Economic Final Report
Words: 1491 Length: 4 Document Type: Term Paper

Economic Systems: An economic system is basically described as specific set of principles that addresses the production, distribution, and consumption of products and services. The involved parties in the production, distribution, and consumptions processes are usually determined by or dependent on the economic system. Throughout the history of humanity, different types of economic systems have evolved because different societies have placed varying emphasis on distinctive goals and priorities as part of

Economics the Keynesian Economic Theorists Follow an
Words: 1698 Length: 6 Document Type: Term Paper

Economics The Keynesian economic theorists follow an economic model that considers three factors in macroeconomic growth. These are income distribution, savings, and investment functions. These factors are derived from the theory's determination of equilibrium in the economy as determined by the relationship between employment, prices, and gross-domestic-product (Padalkina 18). The theory suggests that the economy does not have full employment, autonomous demand-component affect rate of growth, and investment decisions are not

Economics Define Economics Economics Is Defined As
Words: 1813 Length: 6 Document Type: Research Paper

Economics Define economics Economics is defined as the study of how society allocates limited resources and goods (Encyclopedia Britannica, 2009). Resources include inputs such as labor, capital, and land and are used to produce goods. Goods include products such as food and clothing, as well as services such as those of barbers, doctors, and firefighters. Often goods and resources are deemed scarce because of society's demand for them vs. their availability (Stapleford,

Sign Up for Unlimited Study Help

Our semester plans gives you unlimited, unrestricted access to our entire library of resources —writing tools, guides, example essays, tutorials, class notes, and more.

Get Started Now