Nature And Origin Of Corporate Dominance Essay

PAGES
8
WORDS
2277
Cite
Related Topics:

¶ … Corporation Changed from Early 19th to 21st Century? Corporate Change Over Two Centuries

Corporations today manifest a singularity of focus on earnings that enables them to slice unencumbered through consideration for outcomes that do not directly impact profit margins. In the book, The Corporation, Joel Bakan asserts that:

"The corporation's legally defined mandate is to pursue, relentlessly and without exception, its own self -- interest, regardless of the harmful consequences it might cause to others" (Bakan, 2005, p. 9)

Bakan argues that the institutional imperatives of corporations, coupled with their seemingly boundless capacity to become more powerful fosters a pathological orientation to doing business that poses grave economic, political, and social danger. Bakan's theory will serve as the primary touchstone in this exploration of the influence of corporate power on politics and the economy.

The first section of this paper centers on a discussion about the ways in which the economic forces of capitalism and the market society undergird the present power surge of corporations, and lay the groundwork for radical economic change -- some of which seems reminiscent of feudal economic arrangements. A discussion about the mutuality of political power and corporate power is the focus of the second section. This discussion is grounded in Steven Lukes' seminal theories of power, and ideas about the co-opting of government, touching on examples from Canadian history, such as the staples political economy theory. The paper will conclude with a discussion of Herbert Marcuse's pivotal theory: the capacity of consumerism to define what society should desire and strive for over other objectives

Capitalism and the Market Society

Driven to increasingly larger size and influence, corporations treat social responsibility as a set piece: a discrete initiative that results in positive media coverage but that in no way hinders the overarching corporate goal of raising stock prices for shareholders. Free market economists like Milton Friedman advocate for an idealized market based on supply and demand, unencumbered by government control. Put simply, a free market is characterized by a voluntary agreement between two parties who seek to trade goods or services, and mutually agree on price without external intervention. In the free market frame, sellers need not make apologies for greed. Indeed, free market economists are often quoted -- typically with pejorative intent -- as stating "greed is good." And perhaps from an economic point-of-view, to the extent that greed functions as an elemental acquisitive force in trade and development, greed can be cast in a favorable light. For this discrete definition of greed, society does not demand apologies from economists. However, greed that is unanchored by moral values gives tacit -- if not overt -- approval to corporations that seek to maximize profit "regardless of the harmful consequences" (Bakan, 2005, p. 9). In Bakan's corporate purpose statement, we are faced with a collective corporate sentiment that does not embrace as business success the economic development it provides while engaged in making a profit. Nor does this sentiment indicate an interest in "the workers" or give any indication that altruistic values might be attached to the corporate business enterprise. Proponents of a free market share an ideology that undermines corporate interest in social and economic benefit for the common good, and can drive corporations to continually seek ways to increase their power base.

Economic forces undergird the present power surge of corporations and lay the groundwork for radical economic change -- some of which seems reminiscent of feudal economic arrangements. The transformative power of the monetization of land, labor, and capital is evident over the past several centuries, and much of the early thinking about these changes derived from the writings of Adam Smith in the Wealth of Nations. Smith conceptualized human nature as having a particularly robust "desire for betterment," which more modern economists refer to as the profit motive. Through his theory of moral sentiments, Smith asserted that:

The rich...are led by an invisible hand to make nearly the same distribution of the necessaries of life, which would have been made, had the earth been divided into equal portions among all its inhabitants, and thus without intending it, without knowing it, advance the interest of the society...(Smith, 1759, Part IV, Chapter 1).

When reading Smith, it is important to keep top-of-mind that many of the forces that impact the "invisible hand" today, such as marketing, large-scale industry, financial and credit services, were not in place during Smith's time. Many modern theorists suggest that the fundamental economic dynamics that Smith described have changed substantively since the book was written. Indeed, the mechanisms that ensure the system of wealth building will...

...

In Smith's theory of moral sentiments, the seeds of the modern so-called "trickle down theory" postulated by supply-side economists can be seen -- a theory that asserts the supply side (production) of goods and services is fundamental to economic growth.
Terry Slater (2012) writes in The Rise and Spread of Capitalism that as the resident system moved from feudalism to capitalism, people began to experience freedom of choice across many life contexts -- a dynamic that would eventually lead to "consumer sovereignty" and greater prosperity. Slater's theories about geographic and economic dynamics point to the creation of social processes and cultural contexts that act as catalysts for the accumulation of capital in certain locations.

In The Emergence of Market Society, Don Slater and Fran Tonkiss (2001), review the historical evolution of the construct of market society, theorizing that markets are social institutions and not just formal economic models. Slater and Tonkiss (2001) base their theory on contemporary ideas grounded in society, such as social action, order, and relationships. Using frameworks from the social sciences, the authors cobble together cultural, political, and social theory in a manner that distinctly represents the contemporary market. The Slater and Tonkiss (2005) model provides a foundation for understanding the blurring of lines between economic, social, and political life that produced the market society, and the economic mechanics that have evolved to into modern capitalist business structures and environments.

The Mutuality of Political Power and Corporate Power

The concept of business co-opting government is pivotal to comprehending the relationship between contemporary economics and political power. Corporations have shown their willingness to trample anyone and anything that gets in their way -- and, increasingly, politicians are willing to assist with the process. Writing on the sources of corporate power, Ted Nace (2003) listed the following:

[T] he power that large corporations derive from their political action committees, their lobbyists, their lawyers, their control over millions of jobs…the 'revolving door' that moves corporate people in and out of government agencies, the corporate ownership of media conglomerates… [and] the obscure Supreme Court decisions that 'discovered' corporate rights hidden in the language of the Constitution (p.12).

The revolving door between government positions and high-paying employment in private industry has been a difficult, if not impossible, door to shut. With their deep pockets, corporations have been able to increase lobbying to unprecedented levels, pour massive contributions into political campaigns, and conduct public relations campaigns that whitewash their unregulated impact on the environment and society. Corporate power is linked to political outcomes, to the manner in which corporations obfuscate their power and influence, and to the way that corporate power can reshape the judicial and legislative balance of power.

Robert A.G. Monks wrote that society is toe-to-toe with a "situation of great precariousness" in which it is "dangerously close to the co-option of government by business" (Bernasek, 2013). Robert Reich, former U.S. Secretary of Labor in the Clinton administration and U.S. Senator Bernie Sanders of Vermont assert that the U.S. has arrived at this point today. The phenomenon is certainly not particular to modern society; history provides many examples of government being co-opted by the wealthy long before the emergence of the modern corporation. One has only to look as far as Canadian history at the Staples political economy theory to understand the machinations that bring about co-optation. The writings on Harold Innis and the Staple theory illustrate how the search for and exploitation of extracted materials in Canada led to the creation of supportive institutions and shaped the regional and national political culture. The dovetailing of politics and economics is clearly illustrated in this example.

In Power: A Radical View, Steven Lukes (1975) defined two different types of power that he has derived from Spinoza: the capacity to impact the surrounding world and to dominate other beings -- the second power being a subset of the first. Lukes (2005) postulated that there are three dimensions of power that he refers to as: the one-dimensional view, the two-dimensional view, and the three dimensional view. Lukes (1975) seminal work describes a unique conceptualization of power along these three dimensions that are fundamentally related to decision-making and behavior. He defines the first dimension as "the study of concrete, observable behavior" (p. 17, emphasis in original). Thus, the first dimension is seen to be the analysis of observable conflicts…

Sources Used in Documents:

References

Bakan, J. (2005). The corporation. The pathological pursuit of profit and power. New York, NY: Free Press.

Bernasek, A. (2013, July 6). Robert A.G. Monks, crusading against corporate excess. New York, NY: The New York Times. Retreived http://www.nytimes.com/2013/07/07/business/mutfund/robert-ag-monks-crusading-against-corporate-excess.html

Lukes, S. (1975). Power: A radical view. Macmillan, (pp. 11-25).

Marcuse, H. (1964). The new forms of control. In One-dimensional man: Studies in the ideology of advanced industrial society. Beacon Press. 1-18.


Cite this Document:

"Nature And Origin Of Corporate Dominance" (2014, April 01) Retrieved April 19, 2024, from
https://www.paperdue.com/essay/nature-and-origin-of-corporate-dominance-186597

"Nature And Origin Of Corporate Dominance" 01 April 2014. Web.19 April. 2024. <
https://www.paperdue.com/essay/nature-and-origin-of-corporate-dominance-186597>

"Nature And Origin Of Corporate Dominance", 01 April 2014, Accessed.19 April. 2024,
https://www.paperdue.com/essay/nature-and-origin-of-corporate-dominance-186597

Related Documents

Corporate Social Responsibility Literature Review a topic-Corporate Social Responsibility The term 'corporate social responsibility' is a social word that has often taken the world by a storm at its mention. Noya and Clarence (2007) in their book "The social economy: building inclusive economies" offers a succinct description and understanding of what normally takes place and get exemplified at the mention of this term in the business world. Many writers of business journals

Integrated Corporate Communication (ICC) and Corporate Communication (CC) The established limitations are severely customized by globalization: the size of the company (where there is not a major link with the area of the performance, delocalization and outsourcing and being dependent on the network), design of the product and sales (where the relation with the competitors may be competitive cooperative) somewhat similar to the frequency of motor industry), competitive relations of space-time,

Corporate communications involves not just the message, but the idea that communications are managed, and are connected to corporate objectives (Cornelissen, 2004). Therefore, when communication possibilities were limited, corporate options were limited, and one did not see communications management perspectives that advocated the type of intimate connection between communications and corporate strategy that one sees in a modern context (Cornelissen, 2004). What this makes clear is that CC is

Decline of the American Diet
PAGES 15 WORDS 5127

The meat comes from a local independent packing company that doesn't buy beef that has been injected with growth hormones; the buns are from a bakery in Pueblo, Colorado; and two hundred pounds of potatoes are "peeled every morning in the kitchen and then sliced with an old crank-operated contraption." The cooks make $10 an hour, and all other employees earn $8.00 an hour. When asked why the Conway

While Cadbury was initially vulnerable resulting in this take over, Kraft had to borrow heavily to afford the final price of 850p per share. In the coming months and years, Kraft will have to balance against recovering the money put into this acquisition (Wiggins, 2010). A risk, many British politicians and citizens alike fear will mean the end of their signature chocolate in an effort by Kraft to increase

Org Crime Organized crime underwrites the bulk of political, social, and economic history in America. What has often been mentioned in passing as legitimate business activities can and often should be reframed as organized crime, such as the trans-Atlantic slave trade and the colonial mercantilism that it supported (Woodiwiss, 2003). When organized crime is taken out of its Hollywood context, which portrays organized crime as an immigrant problem, some patterns emerge